Category Archives: Human Behavior

Anti-affirmations, when needed – Dothan Eagle

Believe it or not, I work really hard at self-regulation. I realize that sometimes I people at less than an optimal level, so I have a list of daily reminders I use to keep it between the ditches of acceptable human behavior.

Each day, I go through a checklist of dozens of behaviors I should not engage in, some learned by trial and error, others by observational guess work. Some of these include:

It is not okay to offer to bat clean-up if a couple who you are friends with tells you about their struggles with infertility.

When you see couples getting wedding photos shot at Wadlington Park or Porter Park, it is not okay to shout things like, Pull them bangs down, youve got a five-head going on, Put a little tongue in that kiss, its classy! or Olympus? Real photogs shoot Canon.

It is not okay to put on a button-down shirt and a pair of khakis, go to a restaurant, and pretend to be the manager, walking from table to table asking guests about their meals and saying Well, thats servers fired! if they complain about anything.

It is not okay to greet your elders at the gym by saying, What up, Centrum Silver? They are all in better shape than you and could break you like fettuccine.

It is not okay to say, Sucker, you could totally get a new cat for $50 when someone tells you about spending hundreds on a vet bill.

When you see old acquaintances posting wedding anniversary photos online, it is not okay to comment, Jeez, if I knew your standards were that low, I would have asked you out.

When the movie theatre plays the turn off your cellphones and devices message before the film, it is not okay to jump to your feet and point to the other audience members and shout, That means you!

When someone compliments you on being a good listener, its not okay to say, Its because Im not really paying attention.

Carelessness is not an acceptable answer if a child asks you where babies come from.

While helpful, it is not socially acceptable to announce Youve got 10 seconds to get out of here, after that I make no promises, upon walking into a stall in the mens room.

Were all a little crazy. Its just how you manage it thats important.

Suggestions for further corrections to Jim Cooks behavior may be relayed to jcook@dothaneagle.com, where they will be given thoughtful consideration.

The rest is here:
Anti-affirmations, when needed - Dothan Eagle

5 factors raise hospitalization risk for kids with autism – Futurity: Research News

A new study identifies which factors put young people with an autism spectrum disorder (ASD) at high risk of being hospitalized for inpatient psychiatric careincluding factors both related and unrelated to ASD itself.

Children or teens with autism spectrum disorders often come to hospitals when behavioral episodes overwhelm the support that caregivers can provide at homebut resources at hospitals are sometimes limited, too, says Giulia Righi.

The demand is far greater than the number of clinicians, the number of programs, and the number of beds we have, says Righi, a research assistant professor of psychiatry and human behavior at the Warren Alpert Medical School of Brown University, who treats acute care patients with autism spectrum disorders.

The strongest risk factors are not necessarily associated with ASD.

One of the biggest issues is the availability of acute care services such as day hospital programs and inpatient units to support families when their childrens behaviors have escalated to the point of making a situation unsafe at home, at school, or sometimes both, she adds.

Identifying and addressing the factors that make hospitalization more likely, she says, could reduce such instances. Notably, only two of the risk factors identified in the study of patients with an autism spectrum disorder (ASD)their severity of autism symptoms and the degree of their adaptive daily life functioningwere specific consequences of the disorder.

The strongest risk factorsdisrupted sleep, having a mood disorder, and living in a home with a single caregiverare not necessarily associated with ASD.

Our results underscore the importance of a multidisciplinary approach to the assessment and treatment of children and adolescents with ASD that addresses behavioral, psychological and psychiatric, adaptive, sleep, and medical functioning in order to decrease behavioral crises and the utilization of inpatient psychiatric services, Righi and coauthors write in the study published in theJournal of Autism and Developmental Disorders.

The study made unique use of two large datasets with unusually rich information about patients, Righi says: the Autism Inpatient Collection (AIC), which includes data from childrens psychiatric hospitals in six states, and the Rhode Island Consortium for Autism Research and Treatment (RI-CART). Founded in 2013 by a coalition of local institutions including Brown, Bradley Hospital, and Women & Infants Hospital, RI-CART has grown to become a community of about 1,500 patients and their families.

In the research, Righi and her coauthors looked at the AIC records of 218 patients age 4 to 20 who were hospitalized and compared them with 255 age- and gender-matched members of RI-CART who were not hospitalized. By employing statistical analysis techniques, the researchers were able to isolate risk factors that were independently and significantly associated with the risk of hospitalization.

The strongest predictor was the presence of a mood disorder, which was associated with a seven-fold increase in the odds of hospitalization. The presence of sleep problems was the second strongest risk, more than doubling the odds. A high score on a standardized scale of autism symptom severity raised the odds a little bit, though still significantly.

Meanwhile, having a high score on a standardized scale of adaptive functioning, or basic life and coping skills, slightly but significantly lowered the odds of hospitalization. Finally, children and teens in households with married caregivers had only 0.4 times the odds of needing hospital care compared with comparable patients living with only one adult caregiver.

That last result, Righi says, is likely not about family structure or stability per se, but rather about resources available to cope with the care for a child with high needs. The hospitalization risk associated with mood and sleep disorders, meanwhile, points to the need to engage in a broad based and careful psychiatric evaluation of autism patients.

Our findings emphasize the utility of thorough assessment and treatment of mood and sleep conditions to decrease the likelihood of requiring psychiatric hospitalization, Righi and her coauthors write.

Righi notes that some factors she might have hypothesized would be independently significant were not, including the degree of intellectual disability or gastrointestinal problems.

Righi acknowledges that while research examined many factors, others that it didnt measure might also be important. Also, the study measured associations of risk factors with hospitalization but doesnt prove they were the cause of hospital visits.

But the study authors write that the risk factors they identified may be worth addressing before young autism patients reach the point where hospitalization becomes necessary.

In spite of its limitations, the study authors conclude, the present findings reveal indicators that may be useful for identifying children and adolescents at greater risk of psychiatric hospitalization as well as other potential targets for individual and family intervention.

The Hassenfeld Child Health Innovation Institute at Brown University helped to fund the study along with the Simons Foundation, the Nancy Lurie Marks Family Foundation, and the National Institutes of Health.

Source: Brown University

Read the rest here:
5 factors raise hospitalization risk for kids with autism - Futurity: Research News

A Periodic Table of Behavior for Psychology – Psychology Today (blog)

Modern science took off during the Enlightenment and changed the world. Science was differedfrom philosophy in that it did not presuppose how nature must be, as the early philosophers tended to do, but instead scientists got up out of their armchairs and asked questionsand gathered data about howuniverse actually behaved.Observation, measurement and experimentation became the sine qua non of the scientific enterprise, and this has continued into the present day.

Science has been so successful that philosophy has drifted into the background, so much so that some scientists (e.g., E. O. Wilson) have wondered if philosophy is even necessary. This love of empiricism was soaked up by scientific psychologists. In his popular Psych 101 text, David Myers states that the key word in psychologys definition is science and that psychology is less a set of findings than a way of asking and answering questions,meaning that psychologists approach their subject matter through the lens and methods of empirical science.

What is the problem with this?The problemthat emerges is thatthere is no general framework for understanding the concepts and categories under investigation. Consider physics. Prior to Newton, physics was a pre-paradigmatic mess, meaning that the concepts and categories that physicists were using were highly inconsistent. One of the great achievements of Newtonian science was the emergence of a shared definitional system that could be examined empirically. Notice the first part of this sentence. A shared definitional system. That is a key aspect of cumulative science. And it is something physics, chemistry and biology largely have achieved, at least at the core of the discipline. That is, they know generally what matter, energy, electrons, neutrons, genes, cells, evolution and so forth "mean".And is one of the decisive factors that makes themworthy of the name"science".

Psychology completelylacks a shared definitional system. There is NO agreement on terms like behavior, mind, cognition, self, consciousness, and the like. And, with its focus on empiricism, psychology will not achieve such an understanding because observation and experiment alone are not enough to define these terms. What is needed is a holistic map that allows investigators to consider the concepts and categories that are used for understanding.

The concepts and categories that one uses to map reality is ones metaphysical system. The Periodic Table of the Elements is a metaphysical system. It offers a map of the elements, lining them up into different categories. It is a map that is supported by empirical work, but the map itself is metaphysical in nature.

Psychology needs a metaphysical system for understanding as much as it needs empirical research. Without advances in achieving a shared metaphysical system, psychology will continue to exist as a collection of studies that offer interesting glimpses into the human condition, but not deep understanding.

The Tree of Knowledge System offers the field of psychology (and science in general) a metaphysical system from which to operate. Specifically, it offers a clear: (a) cosmology; (b) ontological map of key categories in nature; and (c) epistemological framework for knowledge acquisition.

In terms of cosmology, the ToK System offers a Big History view of the Universe. Consistent with empirical work on the early universe, the ToK System posits that we can understand the universe as an EnergyMatterSpaceTime grid that emerged from a (pure energy) singularity at the Big Bang, approximately 13.8 billion years ago.

In terms of ontology, in the ToK System, Energy is the ultimate substance common denominator. The observable universe is "Energy" in all its different forms (Matter is chunked, frozen energy).The ToK further posits that universe evolves as an unfolding wave of Energy-Information, which, consistent with the Big History formulation, can be placed on the dimensions of time and complexity.

Furthermore, the ToK System posits a general behavioral metaphysics. That is, the ontological essence of the universe can be well-described as change in object-field relationships over time (also characterized as the flow of Energy-Information).

Because the ToK posits the essence of the universe exists as an unfolding wave of Energy-Information, the ToK gives rise to a novel view of primary categories in nature. Specifically, it argues that there are four identifiable dimensions of complexity, which are depicted and labeled Matter, Life, Mind and Culture. These dimensions capture the behavior of 1) objects; 2)organisms; 3)animals and 4)humans. It proposes that these core categories are differentiated because each category behaves in a fundamentally novel way. That is, living objects behave qualitatively differently than inanimate objects. Animal objects behave qualitatively differently than other kinds of organisms. And human objects behave differently than other animals.

According to the ToK, these fundamental divisions exist because of the evolution of different systems of information processing. The storage and processing of information on the DNA molecule gives rise to fundamentally different kinds and levels of self-organization, such that the workings of a cell are qualitatively different than the behavior of organic molecules (and are represented as existing on a separate dimension of self-organization and require a different science, biology, to describe explain and predict).

The emergence of a nervous system in general and brain in particular gave rise to another information processing system that resulted in animal behavior and experiential consciousness, which are qualitatively different behavior patterns than are seen at the level of the cell or molecule. The Mind, Brain, and Behavior sciences (behavioral neuroscience, computational/cognitive neuroscience, comparative psychology, ethology, etc) describe this specificdimension of behavior. The ToK System characterizes these class of sciences basic psychology, although it should be acknowledged that, given the fields institutional history, perhaps this cluster should perhaps just be labeled thesciences ofMind, Brain, and Behavior.

Last, the emergence of language connected human minds together in novel way, giving rise to human culture and societal group organizations that are fundamentally different than is seen in the rest of the animal kingdom.

The general behavioral metaphysics of ToK System gives rise to a Period Table of Behavior, depicted here. A novel feature of the ToK categorization system of these concepts is that it positsthat nature must be divided into both levels (part, whole, group) AND dimensions of complexity (Matter/Objects, Life/Organisms, Mind/Animals, and Culture/Humans).

In terms of epistemology, the ToK System is both empirical and metaphysical, meaning that it emphasizes knowledge acquired through the senses and experiment and emphasizes the need to place such datainto a coherent conceptual framework. It is the union of empirical data with coherent conceptual mapping that provides the most justified knowledge. This can be referred to as a Metaphysical Empirical epistemological position.

The ToK System is consistent with modern physics, chemistry, and biology. It is particularly useful at the level of psychology because it provides a new way to define behavior in general. Behavior is the unfolding wave of Energy-Information. Thus, Matter and Life behave. Psychologists have been horribly confused about this point. The ToK makes the common sense pointthat psychologists are interested in a particular kind of behavior, specifically mental behaviors, which are represented by the third dimension of complexity on the ToK System.Mental behaviorsare the behaviors of the animal as a whole, mediated by the nervous system.In such a formulation, the mind refers to the functional information stored and processed by the nervous system. It is largely synonymous with the broad definition of cognition. Here is a map of the information processing architecture of the human mind.

In the ToK System, experiential consciousness is conceptualized as an embodied whole brain activity that gives rise to experiential awareness, and is well defined and studied empirically by frameworks such as global neuronal workspace theory.

Humans exhibit mental behavior like other animals, but there is an added dimension of complexity. Human language connected human minds, much like the internet connects individual computers (and much like the nervous system connected organ systems in a centralized control center). This results in a qualitative jump in behavioral complexity. Language, along with other technological developments like agriculture, historically set the stage for massive societal/cultural evolutionary changes. As society became more and more complex, large scale belief/justification systems emerged, such as religion, law, and science. Such systems are denoted as Culture with a capital C.

Human self-consciousness is a second order form of consciousness in which the experiential conscious system is reflected upon and narrated, either to ones self (private self-consciousness) or to others (public self-consciousness). The human self-consciousness system functions to build justification systems for ones actions in society. Thus, there are three key domains to human consciousness. An experiential theater of first person awareness, an I-Me second order private self-consciousness system and an I-Thou public self-consciousness system. Here is a map of human consciousness.

Psychologistsstronglyaspire fortheir discipline to be a "real" science. However, to accomplish this dream, psychologists need to realize that empiricism per se is not sufficient. If each researcher continues to operationalize the mind, behavior, cognition, consciousness, or whatever phenomena of interest they are investigating via their own (metaphysical) system of understanding, then, despite the best experiments, all we will have is conceptual mush because there will be no way to relate the findings systematically. The ultimate goal of the field is not to just conduct experiments. It is to build a system of cumulative knowledge about human mental behavior. This is why we need something akin to a Periodic Table of the Elements. The ToK offers the field a Periodic Table of Behavior.

View post:
A Periodic Table of Behavior for Psychology - Psychology Today (blog)

New Season Three Of Invisibilia – Thursday Nights In June 2017 – Valley Public Radio

Invisibilia, Latin for "the invisible things," explores the invisible forces that shape human behavior things like ideas, beliefs, assumptions and emotions. In Season 3 premiering in June hosts Alix and Hanna will delve into the ways our concepts shape our worldviews and how we mold our own reality. You can hear the new season of InvisibiliaThursday nights in June at 8:00 PM, starting June 1, 2017.

Episode 1: Emotion(airing Thursday, June 1) How real and inevitable are our emotions? In the first stories of the new season, we're giving emotions a similar treatment to the one we gave to thoughts in the very first episode of Invisibilia (The Secret History of Thoughts). Where do our emotions come from? How seriously should we take them? Do they tell us truths about the world that should guide our behavior or should we be more skeptical about them? To explore these questions, we look at an unusual case in the American justice system. Then we follow a man as he discovers a new emotion that no one in western culture has experienced before.

Episode 2: Reality Check(airing Thursday, June 8) How real is our own reality? What happens when people can't agree on reality? Many in our increasingly polarized society confront this question every day. In this episode we meet Umpires in training who have a lock on what's really happening and visit a small town in Minnesota, called Eagle's Nest, that has a unique experience with the reality divide: some of the people in the town believe that wild black bears are gentle animals to be fed and befriended, while many others take a more traditional view on the human-bear relationship. This leads to conflict and, ultimately, a tragic death. Then we meet a young man who is taking extraordinary steps to break himself out of his own reality bubble.

Episode 3: The Other Self(airing Thursday, June 15) How does the culture help shape the reality each of us lives in? In this episode we explore a theory about prejudice that has taken hold in recent years: implicit bias. The rise of this concept was facilitated by the public release of a psychological test that can be done online called the Implicit Association Test, which purports to measure a secret, hidden part of ourselves that most of us can't directly access: our racism. Although embraced by many as an incredible breakthrough in our understanding of the human psyche, it has also received pushback from groups and individuals who don't believe that it is accurately measuring bias. In this story we follow the development of the test and theory of implicit bias and talk to several people who are trying to confront and change their other self.

Episode 4: True You(airing on Thursday, June 22) What realities should we entertain for ourselves? In this episode we pose one of our favorite questions to ask children: What do you want to be when you grow up? Many people have these visions of their future selves; fantasies of a smarter, better, richer, more successful version of the people they are today. In many ways these future selves motivate us, pushing us to improve ourselves as we seek to achieve our dreams. But they can also be dangerous, mocking us for everything we have failed to become. Our stories take us into the life of a Syrian orphan who forged a new identity and life despite all odds and we go to North Port, Florida, where the principal of a high school did something unusual, and pretty extreme, to try and help his students reach their full potential, in an experiment that went horribly wrong. Then we travel to another world entirely; the dream world, where a woman is seeking answers from within.

Visit link:
New Season Three Of Invisibilia - Thursday Nights In June 2017 - Valley Public Radio

KPCC reporters fact-check Rep. Dana Rohrabacher and Tom Steyer’s climate claims – 89.3 KPCC

(Above) Tom Steyer introduces a panel during the National Clean Energy Summit 6.0 at the Mandalay Bay Convention Center on August 13, 2013 in Las Vegas, Nevada. (Below) Rep. Dana Rohrabacher of California speaking at CPAC 2011 in Washington, D.C. Isaac Brekken/Getty Images and Gage Skidmore/Flickr/Creative Commons

On June 1, KPCC produced a live on-air special on President Trump's decision to withdraw the United States from the Paris Climate Agreement. We interviewed U.S. Representative Dana Rohrabacher, R-Orange County, and investor and environmental philanthropist Tom Steyer about their views on the decision. Afterwards, we received many comments from listeners who felt we did not sufficiently challenge their claims. KPCC environment reporter Emily Guerin and correspondent Matt Bloom have this fact-check.

Rep. Dana RohrabacherI have no doubt that there are these climate cycles and we go through them and it's only been until recently that the politicians have tried to claim that we have to control people's behavior in order to control those climate cycles. And so I disagree with the theory that CO2, done by mankind, is a major cause for climate change.

KPCCNinety-seven percent of scientists are in agreement that human activities are responsible for global warming trends over the past 100 years. Most of the leading scientific organizations in the world have made public statements in support of this consensus, including the American Association for the Advancement of Science, the American Geophysical Union and the National Academy of Sciences.

Rohrabacher I think the CEOs [Tesla CEO Elon Musk and Disney CEO Bob Igner, who both condemned the President's decision], they don't have to worry about the unemployment the Paris agreement would cause.

The notion that the Paris climate agreement will cause anything is misleading, because the agreement is voluntary. Each country pledges to cut its emissions by a certain amount by a certain year. Every five years, each country reviews where its at and explains why it has or has not hit its targets. But the targets are not legally enforceable. Vox has a great explainer on this topic.

RohrabacherThe people of the Paris accord were insisting on things like the ending of frequent flyer miles, because they see the airplanes just the worst violators.

KPCC cannot find any evidence that the Paris accord mentions ending frequent flyer miles.

Rohrabacher We've had the most incredible, for the last 30 years, how do you say, political campaign to set a mindset in people's consciousness that some way every time there's some problem with the climate and you see a cycle going through, that that in some way has to do with human behavior, and thus there's an excuse to control human behavior. But I know a lot of people have looked into it who have come to this conclusion, and I certainly have, that there is a small impact of the manmade CO2 on the climate.

According to the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, the body of international scientists that regularly scrutinizes climate research, Human influence on the climate system is clear, and recent anthropogenic emissions of greenhouse gases are the highest in history. Recent climate changes have had widespread impacts on human and natural systems.

RohrabacherAl Gore said global warming was going to dramatically increase the sea level. And of course that never happened.

According to the IPCC, sea level rose seven inches between 1901 and 2010. Not only is the sea level rising, but its rising faster than at any time over the past two thousand years. And the rate is only expected to increase in the future.

Tom SteyerI think the president is attempting to make a winner out of the fossil fuel industry when it's in decline.

KPCCSteyer lumps all fossil fuels together here, but its a bit more complicated than that. Coal production is in decline, in part due to the lower costs of natural gas generation and growing market share of wind and solar power, according to the U.S. Energy Information Administration. Last year, the EIA said natural gas provided 33 percent of U.S. energy generation while coals share fell to 32 percent, making 2016 the first year that natural gas-fired generation exceeded coal generation on an annual basis.

Meantime, EIA says production of both natural gas and oil in the U.S. is booming. Since 2012, the U.S. has pumped more oil and gas than any other country in the world.

SteyerI think what we've seen in the marketplace is that renewables plus storage is cheaper than fossil fuels.

When Steyer says "storage," he means the ability to store the electricity produced by solar or wind generation in massive batteries so that the energy is available later, when the wind is no longer blowing or it's cloudy.

The REN21 Renewables Global Futures Report from the United Nations says that renewables are now the least expensive option for new power generation in almost all countries. Butthe limitations of existing infrastructure are abarrier to further expansion.

Steyer It's unrealistic to think that the federal government doesn't have a role to play in our economy. For one thing, they fund an awful lot of research.

A lot of federal research and development grants jump start businesses here in Southern California. For example, the Department of Energys Advance Research Projects Agency-Energy, also known as ARPA-E, gave $2 million to Marine BioEnergy Inc. in La Caada to develop a system for turning kelp into fuel. Other federally funded programs include $1 million for UCLAs effort to build a better battery for electric vehicles. The Trump administration has signaled that it wants to eliminate ARPA-E funding next year.

SteyerBut the fact of the matter is number one, you have to acknowledge the problem (climate change) before you talk about solving it. And number two, we believe that solving it will create better jobs, better paying jobs, and will help the health of Americans. So we not only solve a huge threat to America but we make ourselves better off and healthier.

A 2017 report from the U.S. Department of Energy found that California was home to 40 percent of the country's solar energy jobs, a number that could rise as the state moves toward ambitious renewable energy goals. Since 2004, greenhouse gas emissions in California declined over nine percent while the state's GDP grew 28 percent, according to the California Air Resources Board.

Follow this link:
KPCC reporters fact-check Rep. Dana Rohrabacher and Tom Steyer's climate claims - 89.3 KPCC

Policies are hurting our children – Foster’s Daily Democrat

June 1 - To the Editor:

A number of years ago I was given a T-shirt from New Hampshire Healthy Kids, which I wore proudly. On the back of the shirt was written, "A hundred years from now it will not matter what my bank account was, the sort of house I live in, or the kind of car I drove. But the world may be a different because I was important in the life of a child."

In a hundred years, but most likely much sooner, children will find out that the world they live in is quite different from that of their ancestors, unfortunately, not in a positive way. The actions and policies of Donald Trump's administration, supported by their accomplices in Congress will negatively impact the lives of today's children, and their children for generations to come.

In the short-term, children will be greatly harmed by the health care, educational, nutritional, environmental, economic, anti-science, gun violence and diplomatic policies of Mr. Trump and the Republicans. In almost every department of the federal government, policies have been initiated that will negatively impact the health and safety of children, as well as their economic futures. Polices that limit nutritional support, reduces control of toxins in our environment, cutting scientific research, cutting health care coverage, promoting more guns, even in schools, and cutting drug addition treatment services, to name some of the most obvious. Trump's proposed budget reflects a philosophy that is anti-child and only serves the interest of the very wealthy.

However, the most dangerous act of Mr. Trump was his decision to withdraw the United States from the landmark Paris Climate Accord. This action will place us in a class with the likes of Syria and Nicaragua, the only other non participants in the Paris Climate Accord. Trump and Republicans have long totally denied or have greatly minimized the reality and extent that human behavior is responsible for the warming of the planet, despite the overwhelming consensus of the world's scientific community that human behavior is causing climate change and immediate action is needed to slow the process. As one of the largest polluters in the world, the U.S. is doing huge harm to the planet by withdrawing from the Paris Climate Accord. The message Trump is sending to our people and the world is that we do not believe in science, and we are wiling to gamble the future of our children and our planet for ideological political and destructive economic gains.

Obviously, Trump and his fellow Republicans care much more about the size of their bank accounts, the size of the house they live in and the type of car they drive, than what is important to the health and security of our children and future generations. Their short-term, immediate gratification self interest, "greed is good" mentality will have long-term destructive consequences for generations to follow. Shakespeare wrote, "The evil that men do oft lives after them, the good is interred with their bones." In Trump's and his allies case, their bones will be accompanied by little good, but the world's children will long suffer from the consequences of their evil actions that will live long after them. Their scornful place in history will be appropriately recorded.

Rich DiPentima

Portsmouth

Read the original:
Policies are hurting our children - Foster's Daily Democrat

Teaching Robots "Manners": Digitally Capturing And Conveying Human Norms – ECNmag.com

Advances in artificial intelligence (AI) are making virtual and robotic assistants increasingly capable in performing complex tasks. For these smart machines to be considered safe and trustworthy collaborators with human partners, however, robots must be able to quickly assess a given situation and apply human social norms. Such norms are intuitively obvious to most peoplefor example, the result of growing up in a society where subtle or not-so-subtle cues are provided from childhood about how to appropriately behave in a group setting or respond to interpersonal situations. But teaching those rules to robots is a novel challenge.

To address that challenge, DARPA-funded researchers recently completed a project that aimed to provide a theoretical and formal framework for what norms and normative networks are; study experimentally how norms are represented and activated in the human mind; and examine how norms can be learned and might emerge from novel interactive algorithms. The team was able to create a cognitive-computational model of human norms in a representation that can be coded into machines, and developed a machine-learning algorithm that allows machines to learn norms in unfamiliar situations drawing on human data.

The work represents important progress towards the development of AI systems that can intuit how to behave in certain situations in much the way people do.

The goal of this research effort was to understand and formalize human normative systems and how they guide human behavior, so that we can set guidelines for how to design next-generation AI machines that are able to help and interact effectively with humans, said Reza Ghanadan, DARPA program manager.

As an example in which humans intuitively apply social norms of behavior, consider a situation in which a cell phone rings in a quiet library. A person receiving that call would quickly try to silence the distracting phone, and whisper into the phone before going outside to continue the call in a normal voice. Today, an AI phone-answering system would not automatically respond with that kind of social sensitivity.

We do not currently know how to incorporate meaningful norm processing into effective computational architectures, Ghanadan said, adding that social and ethical norms have a number of properties that make them uniquely challenging. There seems to be an enormous number of these norms, yet they are highly context-specific and only a relevant subset of them get activated, depending on the situation. Moreover, they seem to exist in an organizational hierarchy but can also be activated in horizontal bundlesnetworks of norms tied together by the contexts in which they apply and triggered by certain context-specific features of the world. They can be in conflict with one another but they are also continuously being updated.

Further complicating matters, norms are activated extremely quickly. Thats something we are all familiar with, Ghanadan said, since normal people detect norm violations very quickly! And in people, new norms or their preconditions for activation are learned into the already complex norm network through not just one but rather a variety of modalities, such as observation, inference, and instruction. The uncertainty inherent in these kinds of human data inputs make machine learning of human norms extremely difficult, Ghanadan said.

Ultimately, for a robot to become social or perhaps even ethical, it will need to have a capacity to learn, represent, activate, and apply a large number of norms that people in a given society expect one another to obey, Ghanadan said. That task will prove far more complicated than teaching AI systems rules for simpler tasks such as tagging pictures, detecting spam, or guiding people through their tax returns. But by providing a framework for developing and testing such complex algorithms, the new research could accelerate the day when machines emulate the best of human behavior.

If were going to get along as closely with future robots, driverless cars, and virtual digital assistants in our phones and homes as we envision doing so today, then those assistants are going to have to obey the same norms we do, Ghanadan said.

At some point, it may even be a robot behind that desk at the library, raising its finger and saying, Shhhh!

The work was conducted by researchers at Brown University and Tufts University, led by Bertram Malle at Brown.

See the original post:
Teaching Robots "Manners": Digitally Capturing And Conveying Human Norms - ECNmag.com

Not Quite Rational Man – City Journal

For more than a century, neoclassical theory dominated economic thinking. Neoclassical economics is a theory based on three key assumptions: individuals have rational preferences; individuals maximize utility, while firms maximize profits; and people choose independently, based on available information. As with any widely adopted theory, neoclassical economics has huge merits, but it also suffers from important shortcomings.

One increasingly acknowledged flaw of neoclassical theory is its oversimplified model of human nature, known by academics as homo-economicus. Homo-economicus is an efficient calculating machine, someone who always knows what he wants and how to get it (that is, he knows his utility and how to maximize it). But people dont always know what they want, and if they do, they dont know why they want it or how to get it. Humans are not cold, rational calculators. They are emotional beings, tricked easily with math; but they are also incredibly creative and fantastic social learners. Is it possible to build an economic theory that takes humans as they are? Or is the complexity of the economy too great for there ever to be a theory that includes the more esoteric aspects of human behavior, such as social learning, emotions, and imagination?

The good news is that, when it comes to building such a theory, economists do not have to work alone. For decades, scholars from a variety of disciplines have been exploring the consequences of these less rational aspects of human behavior. As the ideas of these outsiders have begun to penetrate the economic community, they have given rise to what I call post-neoclassical economics. This is a body of knowledge that incorporates not only the findings of psychiatrists and behavioral scientists but also those of evolutionary geographers, sociologists, anthropologists, political scientists, historians, development experts, and even some physicists. These nontraditional thinkers have explored the role of social networks and political institutions, as well as innovation, imagination, and collective learning in our study of the economy.

Neoclassical economics succeeded by translating the world into an accepted paradigm, which was delineated by some foundational assumptions. Post-neoclassical economics, by contrast, is a more methodologically agnostic approach, which considers rational agency as just one of many possible models of human behavior. Indeed, what unifies the post-neoclassical approach is the desire to understand economic behavior using any empirically valid methods, no matter in what field they originated. Evolutionary geographers, for example, will borrow methods from, say, network science, if that helps them improve their grasp of regional economic diversification. Behavioral economists dont hesitate to draw on psychology. These interdisciplinary dialogues create bridges that promote learning and advance our knowledge of how economies operate.

In recent decades, some post-neoclassical work has emerged as a new economic mainstream. The research of psychologists like Daniel Kahneman and of political scientists like Elinor Ostrom has been validated with the highest honor in the economics field: the Nobel Prize. Of course, describing all of post-neoclassical economics is beyond the scope of a single essay. So here I will explore just a few examples of the emerging post-neoclassical paradigm. First, Ill focus on the study of the economic consequences of emotion, now a relatively mature field. Then I will venture into more uncharted territory, which includes the study of imagination and of collective learning.

The study of emotions and their impact on decision making was pioneered by psychologists, including Kahneman, Amos Tversky, Dan Ariely, Jonathan Haidt, and Daniel Gilbert. Their theories initially met resistance from economists, despite being empirically valid. Part of this resistance is explained in an essay by Milton Friedman, who argues that the assumptions of economic theory dont have to be empirically valid, as long as they predict the behaviors observed. The analogy he uses is that of an expert billiards player, who performs as if he were skilled at calculating the trajectories of balls using the laws of physicseven if he knows nothing about physics. A physicist could do a reasonable job of explaining the players actions in the game. Economic models, Friedman says, can similarly be empirically wrong about the actual motivations of economic actors, but justifiable if they predict their behavior correctly. Some neoclassical theorists use Friedmans analogy to defend the use of empirically invalid models of human behavior. Yet for that argument to be right, we would have to reject economics as a science. I think that would be too much to lose.

Instead, I suggest that we borrow from the epistemology of physics, psychology, and computer science, and reinterpret the billiards analogy in that light. A physicist modeling the trajectory of a billiard ball would not claim to have a model of the player but rather, one only of the ball. A psychologist or computer scientist, on the other hand, would probably argue that the billiards player performed the calculations implicitly, by an intuitive system that is accurate but nonnarrativelike the neural networks involved in deep learning, if you are a computer scientist, or using what Kahneman calls system one, if you are a psychologist.

Most scientists, in my experience, agree that no theory, including economic theory, can be excused from empirical testing of its underlying assumptions (even if Friedman says that it should). Think of the Higgs boson (a.k.a. the God particle), which high-energy physicists used for half a century as a theoretical construct to perform calculations. Yet they never accepted the Higgs boson as real until it was confirmed in experiments at CERN, the European Organization for Nuclear Research, in a feat that required a 27-kilometer-long tunnel at the border of France and Switzerland. What makes science science is not the use of mathematical theories but the experiments and observations that validate the theories.

Economics is a sciencea beautiful scienceand is thus subject to this principle. (See Economics Does Not Lie, Summer 2008.) One of the unifying ideas of post-neoclassical economists has been to prioritize empirical findings over theories. If the theory does not match the empirical finding, the theory has to go.

Psychologists have been at the forefront of deepening our understanding of human decision making and how emotions shape our choices. In his 2006 book Stumbling on Happiness, Daniel Gilbert considers both emotions and imagination to explain how our thoughts are distorted when we think about the future and the past. By citing a range of experiments and crafting clever analogies, Gilbert shows that when humans think about the past or the future, they fill in the blanks automatically and unconsciously. We suffer from presentism, a cognitive bias that limits our ability to imagine ourselves as hungry when were full or as happy when were sad. Ultimately, the way we see the future or evaluate the past is based on hedonic assessments, where our present feelings are powerful factors that we cannot ignore. Our choices do not represent coldhearted rational calculations; were decision-making agents whose choices are inevitably influenced by our present emotions.

One of the unifying ideas of post-neoclassical economists has been to prioritize empirical findings over theories.

Jonathan Haidts work also explores the role of emotions in decision making, though he focuses sharply on moral choicesdecisions in which the answer is good or bad, instead of true or false, or a number. Making moral choices requires performing mental acts that are quite different from, say, calculating the cost of a 5 percent interest rate on a 20-year mortgage. Moral choices are complex computations that scholars have tried to explain for centuries, using one of two hypotheses. The first, the rationality-first hypothesis, assumes that humans assess the consequences of their moral choices by anticipating whom an action will harm and how bad the damage will be. This resembles how a neoclassical economic model would operate: here, humans are harm-minimizers who construct behavioral heuristics encoding their rational decision making.

The second hypothesis of moral choice is that humans do not think rationally first but that they make quick emotional decisions that their brains later rationalize, composing a narrative in support of the choice. In this emotions-first view, rationality is like a lawyer hired to justify decisions made by our feelings. So when psychologists ask one of their cleverly crafted, albeit sometimes weird, moral questionsis it wrong to have sex with a frozen chicken (if nobody sees you)?we get a gut feeling justifying our answer first (yes, its wrong!) and a stream of words justifying it later. In his book The Righteous Mind, Haidt presents evidence that the emotions-first mechanism is the dominant way by which we make moral choices.

More examples of the importance of emotions in human behavior can be found in the work of Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky, the famous duo who begot the field of behavioral economics. Here, I will focus on just one of their contributions: prospect theory, which explains some common, yet extreme, situations, where neoclassical economic theory failsfor example, when people buy lottery tickets or pay large settlements for frivolous lawsuits. Neoclassical economics fails to explain these situations because it assumes that, in uncertain situations, people will pay the expected value of an item. For instance, in a lottery with 1 million tickets, and a prize of $1 million, neoclassical theory predicts that people should buy tickets only when they cost less than one dollar. In a frivolous lawsuit, where people have only a 1 percent chance of losing $1 million, neoclassical theory predicts that settlements should not be larger than $10,000. But the fact that people buy lottery tickets at prices higher than their expected value, and settle frivolous lawsuits by paying more than their expected loss, tells us that we do not weigh our decisions using their expected economic value, at least in these extreme situations.

Prospect theory says that the connection between decision weight and expected values is not linear, as neoclassical economics would have predicted, but S-shaped. That means that people deviate from rationality when the cost of a decision is small and the potential benefit is large (lottery tickets), or when the loss is unlikely but could be substantial (the frivolous lawsuit). The frivolous-lawsuit calculation is an example of loss-aversion, the psychological bias that makes people value the things they have at roughly 2.5 times the value of those same things when they dont have them. Emotional attachment is pricey and real.

Cognitive biases like those embodied in Kahneman and Tverskys prospect theory, or the presentism described by Gilbert, are so numerous that some people see their sheer number as discrediting behavioral economics. In other words, the existence of such a large number of biases prevents the development of a single coherent theory. Yet for me, this embarrassment of empirical riches is a sign of progress. Consider particle physics. Decades ago, a myriad of particles had been discovered, but physicists at first didnt know how to assimilate them into a single model. Now, all these particles are seen as a manifestation of a few quarks, leptons, and bosons. Psychology today faces a similar abundance of findings, but the wealth of new evidence is not reason for despair; rather, it provides the fertile empirical ground that post-neoclassical economics needs to model human behavior more accurately. As some have suggested, these biases could be manifestations of shortcuts that evolved to help us make quick decisions in an information-deprived social environment. Id bet that, over the next few decades, some plausible unifying theories will be proposed in this field.

In neoclassical economics, agents use their imagination to make purchasing and production decisions. In reality, people use their imagination for far more than just commercial strategic choices. In fact, one could argue that the main contribution that imagination makes to the economy is creative instead of strategic: imagination is more important to help us design products than to help us decide what products to exchange.

The creative aspects of imagination, however, are not the bread and butter of neoclassical theory. Creativity and imagination can seem flimsy and hard to define. Nevertheless, three recent books have examined the role of imagination in the economy: Yuval-Noah Hararis Sapiens (2014), Joseph HenrichsThe Secret of Our Success(2015), and my own Why Information Grows (2015). The authors of these three books are all outsiders to economics: Harari is trained as a historian, Henrich is an anthropologist, and I am a physicist. One could see this as a limitation. But others may value the fact that people trained in wide-ranging disciplines are making an effort to contribute to economics.

In Sapiens, Harari examines the imagination-based origins of human institutions, from religions to corporations. This is an important topic, since institutions have been a difficult nut to crack (though many attempts have been made, including the research of Douglas North and the institutional economics of Ronald Coase and Oliver Williamson). Harari notes that shared beliefs play an important role in society because they facilitate cooperation among strangers. Take religion, one of his chief examples. People who believe in the same God share expectations about moral choices and agree on rituals and behaviors. God is, in an empirical sense, imaginary, but the concept of a deity serves a powerful coordination purpose nevertheless. Similarly, Harari sees institutions as shared imaginings that humans construct collectively, thanks to the inventive capacities of human languagean important feature differentiating human languages from animal communication systems. By creating common worlds through narratives and stories, we can coordinate our activities more effectively. In Hararis view, institutions were born during the cognitive revolution, some 70,000 years ago, and humans developed imaginative language and could begin sharing worldviews. Imagination is thus a precondition for the emergence of human institutions.

Hararis ideas resonate with Henrichs in The Secret of Our Success, which emphasizes that human success is not a simple result of our species superior intelligenceespecially since, in important ways, our intelligence isnt superior to that of other primates. Our success, rather, hinges on our ability to learn from others and on our ability to accumulate knowledge through generations. Our success isnt solely the result of individual intelligence but a consequence of collective forms of intelligence, powered by social learning. Humans, Henrich argues, accumulate cultural packages of adaptive behaviors. Groups with superior cultural packages, he explains, outcompete other groups, making social learning adaptive. But because cultural packages are hard to explain, their transmission usually involves mysterious or not fully understood rituals that people adopt: taboos, songs, and myths, for instance, which might be literally inaccurate but are evolutionarily useful because of the adaptive knowledge that they help convey. In Henrichs view, the institutions emphasized by Harari are adaptive when they aid in the intergenerational transmission of knowledge.

Henrich teaches us that our ability to imagine solutions to adaptive problems, or to understand why these solutions work, is individually very limited, and therefore has evolved to be tacitly collaborative. As a species, we have not historically relied on our individual ingenuity or rationality but on wisdom, the accumulation of ingenuity developed through generations and transmitted through rituals, some of which seem bizarrelike adding ashes to corn before you eat it, or narratives about why people should share meat after huntingbut have proved decisive for the survival of some groups. Once again, imagination is crucial, since it not only helps provide the narratives that perpetuate the ritual across generations but also because over long periods, imagination is what our species truly accumulates. The growth that preceded the modern pecuniary expansion of economies is that of accumulated wisdom and imaginationwhat some would call culture.

Hararis and Henrichs books contribute to our understanding of imagination in the context of human institutions and adaptive culture. Why Information Grows, on the other hand, focuses on the role of imagination in the context of products and economic growth. Economists have habitually considered products as widgets that people exchange to create value, or mathematically, as points in a continuum. But products are far from abstract; they have specific uses (have you tried brushing your teeth with a shoe?). In Why Information Grows, I develop a more granular theory of what products are and how our ability to make them shapes the economy.

Comparing the world of early hominids with our modern world can help us understand the economic relevance of imagination and products. The atoms available to cavemen were the same that we have today, but our world looks extremely different from theirs. What changed? Two things: the way in which those atoms are arranged; and our ability to arrange atoms. Products are not actually made of those atoms but from the physical order that they embody. The same plastic can be used to create a spoon or a comb, just as the same tree can be used to create four chairs or one table. The homes, cars, subways, and refrigerators that we associate with prosperity are made of physical order, begot first as imagination. I refer to that physical order as information and to our capacity to create physical order as computation. Economies are computers that not only calculate prices, as Friedrich Hayek would have said, but that also rearrange atoms to create products.

But why create products? Because, by embodying imagination in matter, we can communicate the practical uses of our knowledge. We live in a world where we constantly use products that we do not know how to make but that make our lives easier. We can communicate at long distances, fly across the world, and enjoy quality entertainment, not because we ourselves know how to manufacture planes, build global communication networks, or make movies but because other people do. And that is true for all of us, since most of the time, we are consuming things made by people who know things that we dont. By creating products, we multiply the number of people who can benefit from the knowledge and know-how embodied in only a few individuals. Products can communicate uses in ways that words cannot. They represent a different form of communication, essential to understanding economic growth. In this view, economic growth represents our ability to transform useful imagination into reality at scale.

Ultimately, then, a better conceptualization of the role of imagination in the economy involves thinking of imagination in the context of, first, shared beliefs that help us coordinate our activities with others; and, second, the embodied information that allows products to distribute the practical uses of knowledge and know-how.

Can we put these two ideas together? Since creating products is difficult, because making them requires more knowledge than what any single individual possesses, humans need to create networks to accumulate that knowledge and know-how. The creation of these networks is facilitated by the institutions and rituals described by Harari and Henrich but also by the products that we make, since many of these involve devices that augment our communication and transportation capacities. So by embodying imagination into the institutions that help us form cooperative networks, and by embodying imagination into the products that augment our capacity to interact, we expand the capacity of these networks and ignite economic growth. In fact, the diversity and sophistication of a countrys products accurately predict future economic growthcontrary to what neoclassical trade theory would predict, seeing products as epiphenomenal, rather than central to economic development.

Is there a future for this unwieldy, sprawling post-neoclassical field? I believe that there is. Of course, I myself feel part of it, so I might have a vested interest. Nonetheless, I believe that the field is valuable and that several recent developments confirm that it will have a place in our economic thinking.

First, economics is undergoing a generational change. Decades ago, heterodox views of economicsand the scholars advancing themwere excluded from the academic elite and the worlds most prestigious institutions. The most famous example of this marginalization was the ousting of Sam Bowles from Harvard in a highly contested tenure case in the early 1970s. Bowles, Herbert Gintis, and others packed their bags and moved to Amherst, where they started a successful program in heterodox economics that has produced decades of quality research. Bowles and Gintis, important pioneers of behavioral economics, were deeply interested in human behavior and on the conditions under which people cooperate. Also, they were interested in how people acquired preferences through social learning, since they were unhappy assuming utility functions as given.

Nearly 50 years later, things have dramatically changed. Now, behavioral economists are hot in the academic market, and every economics department wants to employ at least one. Most of these new behavioral economists, like Sendhil Mullainathan at Harvard or Dean Karlan at Yale, are relatively young. These Generation X thinkers are serving as models for a new generation of economists, now in graduate schools, who are more willing to challenge the neoclassical tradition. These new generations are looking for niches to make a contribution, and areas once excluded from the economics mainstream provide the most fertile territory for the establishment of a new camp.

This generational shift has also been strong in policy-oriented organizations like the World Bank, the OECD, and even the IMF. Decades ago, these organizations were almost exclusively neoclassical in orientation, but now they are also populated by nontraditional thinkers. The shift in these organizations is important because it means that post-neoclassical economists have leverage within the worlds leading policymaking organizations.

The diversity and sophistication of a countrys products accurately predict future economic growth.

The deepening maturation of post-neoclassical thinking has also made the field increasingly relevant. Behavioral economics doesnt just explore the quirkiness of human behavior; it also makes clear recommendations about how to nudge human behavior in (ideally) beneficial ways. The post-neoclassical toolbox goes far beyond this, however. Behavioral psychologists and economists have developed a formal understanding of how the framing of problems affects peoples decisions, even in situations that could be perceived as equivalent, at least from a neoclassical point of view. Too many case studies exist in which simple monetary incentives backfirefor example, the preschool in Israel that started charging parents who picked up their children late, only to see parents arriving even later.

The post-neoclassical approach has also become relevant in the context of innovation systems and regional economic diversification. For decades, as Ive noted, neoclassical economics has struggled to account for innovation, beyond mathematically abstracting it as an important secret sauce. Evolutionary economists, from Richard Nelson and Sidney Winter to Ron Boschma, Marianna Mazzucato, and yours truly, have developed empirically validated theories of the process of economic diversification showing that a regions productive structure is deeply affected by innovation policy. This literature, which views economic development as a form of collective learning rather than as the consequence of the accumulation of factors, has helped revive interest in some forms of industrial policy and encouraged the development of tools to assess the economic potential of countries and regions.

Finally, post-neoclassicalism also drew strength from the 2008 financial crisis, which encouraged criticism of the neoclassical tradition for not being more self-critical. Consider the abstract of this 2010 paper by Ricardo Caballero from MIT: The current core of macroeconomics . . . has become so mesmerized with its own internal logic that it has begun to confuse the precision it has achieved about its own world with the precision that it has about the real one. This is dangerous for both methodological and policy reasons. More recently, Paul Romer, now chief economist of the World Bank, made global ripples with a paper critiquing neoclassical macroeconomics.

Of course, neoclassical economists will not lose their place in history. After all, theirs has been a useful theory. But as economics continues to progress, the neoclassical tradition will need to become more comfortable sharing the spotlight with other theories that succeed where neoclassical theory fails. My bold prediction is that new historical figures will emerge in economics and that they will include people from the post-neoclassical field. These individuals might include those who bloomed at the economics fringe during the last generationpeople like Kahneman, Bowles, Mark Granovetter, Tversky, Ostrom, and Gintisbut also those who still have their best work ahead of them.

Csar A. Hidalgo is an associate professor at MIT, director of the Collective Learning group at the MIT Media Lab, and the author of Why Information Grows: The Evolution of Order, from Atoms to Economies.

Illustrations by Ryan Peltier

Read the original post:
Not Quite Rational Man - City Journal

Coyote bites 5-year-old girl in Scottsdale park – AZCentral.com

Kelsey Mo, The Republic | azcentral.com Published 12:29 p.m. MT May 31, 2017 | Updated 10 hours ago

A coyote was caught on Robbie Hackett's dash camera as it ran across the street in Gilbert. azcentral.com

1 of 3

Marilyn McLauchlan talks about recent coyote encounters and her efforts to keep them away Wednesday, March 16, 2016 in Sun City Grand, Ariz.

2 of 3

Scottsdale police help rescue a coyote that got stuck in a resident's fireplace.

3 of 3

Coyote caught on car dash camera

How to keep coyotes away from family and pets

Scottsdale police free coyote from fireplace

This coyote, wandering through a parking area at Mesa Community College, may be late for class, but is probably hunting for food.(Photo: Michael Chow/The Republic)

A young girl was treated and released from a hospitalafter being bitten by a coyote at a Scottsdale park, according to the Arizona Game and Fish Department.

The 5-year-old girl was bitten in the thigh whileplaying Tuesday night at Thompson Peak Park with her mother and two younger siblings.

She had been sitting at the edge of a slide with a granola bar in her hand, unaware that a coyote was resting in the shade underneath, officials said.

"There's no way for us to speculate on whether that (the granola bar)had anything to do with the bite, but it's definitely something for people to be aware of," saidAmy Burnett, a Game and Fish spokeswoman.

The girl did not need stitches and was released from the hospital after undergoing precautionary treatment for rabies, Burnett said.

MORE: Have you seen a coyote in your neighborhood lately? Heres why

Game and Fish employees killeda coyotethey found in the park near Loop 101 and Hayden Road on Tuesday night, and Burnett said that she received word from a contractor with Game and Fish that a second coyote had been removed from thearea Wednesday morning.

"Witnesses said they've seen up to three coyotes ... inthe vicinity of the park," Burnett said.

Given the unusual behavior of the coyote approaching humans, Burnett said, there is a high chance that it was being fed in the neighborhood.

"Fed coyotes become accustomed to people," she said. "They come around a little too close, they become bold, and it can sometimes lead to a situation where animals and humans interact negatively, and it's a good reminder for everyone not to feed wildlife."

Though it is not uncommon for coyotes to be inthe areabecause of its close proximity to open space, human behavior could keep them coming around more often, Burnett said.

Several factors in the urban area, including the water,grass and access to food in the park area invite coyotes to approach humans and creates this cycle where coyotes view humans as a good thing.

"The best thing to do is to leave them wild," Burnett said. "When you feed them, you're changing their behavior, and they're no longer the animals you want to see in our desert roaming free. It never works out well for the people or for the animals."

READ MORE:

A look back at 20 great albums released in 1967

Collision between bicycle, commercial truck turns deadly in Gilbert

New-home sales in Phoenix area up 22 percent; rising prices are not far behind

Read or Share this story: http://azc.cc/2rFzuT0

Original post:
Coyote bites 5-year-old girl in Scottsdale park - AZCentral.com

Understanding anthropogenic effects on space weather – MIT News

Effects of human behavior are not limited to Earth's climate or atmosphere; they are also seen in the natural space weather surrounding our planet. "Space weather" in this context includes conditions in the space surrounding Earth, including the magnetosphere, ionosphere, and thermosphere.

A recent survey by a team of scientists including Phil Erickson, assistant director of MIT Haystack Observatory, has resulted in an article in the journal Space Science Reviews. The study provides a comprehensive review of anthropogenic, or human-caused, space weather impacts, including some recent findings using NASA's Van Allen Probes twin spacecraft.

As space scientist James Van Allen discovered in the 1950s and 1960s, two radiation belts surround Earth with a slotbetween them. The inner edge of the outer Van Allen radiation belt is particularly interesting, as it is composed of high-energy "killer" electrons that have the potential to permanently damage spacecraft. Tracking the inner edge of the radiation belt is important for GPS navigation, communication, and other satellite-based systems to help protect them from this naturally occurring radiation.

Until recently, it was thought that the inner edge of the outer belt was under nearly all conditions located at the plasmapause, the outer boundary of cold, dense plasma surrounding Earth that is produced daily by the sun's extreme ultraviolet rays. During geomagnetic storms, extra energy from solar flares and coronal mass ejections interact with and compress the plasmasphere. Scientists originally thought that under these conditions, the inner edge of the outer Van Allen belt would contract with the compression of the plasmasphere and move closer to Earth.

Research using the Van Allen Probes has discovered instead that during particularly intense geomagnetic storms, the inner edge of the outer belt does not follow suit but instead keeps its distance from the Earth, holding off the inner extent of "killer electrons" possessing damage potential. This inner limit to high-energy electrons occurs at the edge of strong human-origin radio transmissions created for a very different purpose.

Space weather which can include changes in Earth's magnetic environment is usually triggered by the sun's activity, but recently declassified data on high-altitude nuclear explosion tests have provided a new look at the mechanisms that set off perturbations in that magnetic system. Such information can help support NASA's efforts to protect satellites and astronauts from the natural radiation inherent in space.

Video: Genna Duberstein/NASA Goddard Space Flight Center

Strong very low frequency (VLF) radio waves have been used for nearly a century to communicate with submarines, as they penetrate seawater well. But in addition to traveling through the ocean, the VLF waves also propagate upward along magnetic field lines and form a "bubble" of VLF transmissions, reaching to about the same spot that the ultra-relativistic electrons seem to stop during superstorms. The communications signals can interact with and remove some of these high-energy particles through loss to our atmosphere. This new understanding implies that human-origin systems can have an unexpected effect on high-energy space weather around our planet during these unusual, intense storms in space.

The Space Science Reviews survey also explores a more direct effect caused by humans on the near-Earth space environment. High-altitude nuclear detonation tests during the Cold War also affected the near-Earth environment by creating long-lasting artificial radiation belts that disrupted power grids and satellite transmissions. Such tests are now banned: In particular, the 1963 Partial Test Ban Treaty signed by all nuclear powers at the time specifically prohibits nuclear weapons testing in the atmosphere. However, a large body of information on the effects of these atmospheric tests exists, and the article examines these historical nuclear explosions to further study of anthropogenic effects on space weather.

Understanding human-origin space weather under these extreme conditions allows us to greatly enhance our knowledge of natural effects and allows essential engineering and scientific work aimed at protecting the planet's ground-based and satellite technology. Nuclear atmospheric tests were a human-generated and extreme example of some of the space weather effects frequently caused by the sun, says Erickson. If we understand what happened in the somewhat controlled and definitely extreme conditions caused by one of these man-made events, and combine it with studies into longer term effects such as the VLF communications 'bubble,' we can more readily advance our knowledge and prediction of natural variations in the near-space environment.

The work highlights the importance of continuing research into space weather both naturally occurring effects and those influenced by human behavior as an essential part of society's advance toward a more complex, spacefaring society.

Here is the original post:
Understanding anthropogenic effects on space weather - MIT News